Federal Transportation Policy: A Net Destroyer of National Wealth?

by James A. Bacon

“The U.S. highway trust fund is broke,” declares a new report, “Road to Recovery,” published by the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. If you include deferred maintenance, the U.S. surface transportation system added between $103 billion and $175 billion annually to the national deficit in recent years.

The United States is one of only a  few countries in the world where revenues raised to support the federal transportation system do not cover costs. Revenues represent only 62% of surface transportation expenditures — compared to 100% or more among all other members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. And that doesn’t even take into account the U.S.’s bad habit of deferring maintenance, which can increase upkeep to as much as $800,000 per lane-mile over the life of the road.

The report makes another important point: “The rate of economic return from investment in highway infrastructure in the United States has been approaching the long-term interest rate (cost of capital) since the 1990s. Once the rate of economic return meets the long-term interest rate, it becomes equally beneficial to keep invested capital in the private sector, a clear signal that those investments could be without merit. At that point, the system no longer delivers the benefits necessary to justify public funds.” (Click on graph below for more legible image.)

Net ROI in transportation compared to long-term interest rates

Put in the starkest of terms, the U.S. is spending too much on new road/highway construction and too little on maintenance. The Carnegie report doesn’t put the point quite this baldly, but it’s entirely possible that the federal government’s transportation policies could represent a net destroyer of national wealth!

Such madness should come as no surprise. As the report also says, “While the country suffers the effects of an increasingly degraded and under-performing transportation system, investment decisions on the nation’s transportation system have  become increasingly unfocused, short-term and highly politicized.” In 1987, President Ronald Reagan vetoed a transportation funding bill because it contained 100 earmarks. In 2005, President George W. Bush signed a funding bill containing 6,229 earmarks.

How, then, do we fix this broken-down system? The authors advocate assessing a 5% ad valorem tax on oil  production and imports when the world oil price is rising and a tax on retail gasoline sales when the world oil price is falling. The idea has some merits, although I’m not entirely persuaded. What fascinates me most is the report’s discussion of the true cost of federal transportation policy.

The authors tote up the following when calculating how much the U.S. is underfunding its transportation system (figures are from the “high” scenario): $85 million in deferred maintenance, $20 billion in federal General Fundsubsidies, $40 billion in hidden budgetary costs paid by agencies other than the U.S. Department of Transportation, a $29 billion productivity loss from sub-optimal investment, and interest payments on debt from General Fund expenditures.

What concerns me most — because it is a problem that Virginia shares — is deferred maintenance. States the report:

Studies have found that spending $5 million on preventive maintenance can save $100 million to $500 million in rehabilitation and reconstruction costs. Although postponing maintenance may appear inescapable given the current shortfall of transportation funds, this deferred maintenance will cost America dearly; projections place its cost at a staggering $5 trillion by 2035 (in 2010 dollars). It is estimated that it would cost three times the transportation system’s $1.4 trillion present asset value to replace it if it were not kept in a state of good repair.

In case you missed it, I refer you to my recent discussion of life cycle budgeting, which encompasses both the up-front capital costs of transportation projects and long-term maintenance costs. The Commonwealth Transportation Board is scheduled to discuss “local maintenance programs” in its upcoming meeting this Wednesday. I will be interested to see how presenters frame the issue.


Share this article



ADVERTISEMENT

(comments below)



ADVERTISEMENT

(comments below)


Comments

11 responses to “Federal Transportation Policy: A Net Destroyer of National Wealth?”

  1. “local maintenance programs” as in devolution?

    🙂

  2. an interesting metric perhaps would be how much Americans pay per capita for transportation verses how much Europeans and Japanese do….

    I have the give some states credit for trying to keep the interstates maintained … but it’s maddening for them to close off one or both lanes for miles and miles… creating these long trains of vehicles .. with the slowest vehicle determining the top speed for everyone behind him.

  3. If the revenues don’t meet expenditures where does the money come from? I assume it must be borrowing, but it isn’t clear.

    Anyway, if other countries are paying 100% in cash, they are nuts. Why charge existing residents full fare for an asset that will be used up over a long period?

  4. I am glad to see you have picked up on life cycle cost analysis, something I have harped on for years. For example, if a life cycle analysis is applied, the argument that residential construction is a money loser for local govt goes out the window.

    However, life cycle costing is only one element of a full systems analysis. Which is what is required to determine net social utility.

  5. Groveton Avatar

    ““The rate of economic return from investment in highway infrastructure in the United States …”.

    I love it when some group takes a subjective matter and dresses it up like a T-Bill analysis.

    What is the value I receive by being able to drive to Clemson University and visit my son at college?

    Hydra makes the best point in the comments regarding life cycle costing and the value of residential construction. In Northern Virginia there is a fairly determined effort by some to severely curtail residential development. Whether it’s the zoning in Loudoun County or the so-called Rural Crescent in Prince William County, the anti-building sentiment is growing. One argument always used is the belief that new construction results in higher taxes since the new residences don’t pay for themselves with sufficient taxes. I questioned one person on that theory with an extreme argument – if Bill Gates built a house in the county and moved here would it really be a net financial defecit? The answer was “no”. Houses that cost $500,000 or more are a net financial gain. Apparently, the anti-building folks find no irony by standing in front of the $300,000 house they bought new in 2005 insisting that residential construction of homes under $500,000 is bad.

    Hydra – any ideas where one might find life cycle costing analyses for residential construction?

  6. Groveton Avatar

    My comment was so insightful I thought it should be repeated. With WordPress one has to resist the temptation to keep pressing enter when the response is slow. All the “enters” queue up and are processed, one aftr another, as updates.

    My bad.

  7. Whether new residential construction pays its own way is largely dependent on whether the new household has children in public schools. Let’s assume the new house is located in Fairfax County and is assessed at $500 K. The current tax rate is 1.07 per $100. This house would produce $5350 in real estate taxes. FCPS spends an average of $12,28o per student and local taxpayers pick up 71.2% of those costs or $8743 per student. With one child in public school, our example falls short. I would guess, but do not know, that the analysis would hold true for other counties and cities in Virginia. Thus, we have local government lusting for commercial growth.
    But, in all fairness, there is a cost in increased transportation needs for commercial development and we all need to live somewhere, so there does, of course, need to be some balance between commercial and residential development.

  8. Groveton Avatar

    TMT:

    Your example is analysis in parts. Yes, the real estate taxes are insufficient to pay for the one student in public school. However, the home presumably generated jobs while it was being built and sales of the things in the home – all of which were taxed. The owners presumably pay income taxes and each sale of the home generates more real estate sales taxes.

    Hydra is right about life cycle costing. However, I would add life cycle tax generation. The fact that Virginia is a train wreak in how it collects and distributes tax money around the state doesn’t make residential development dilutive to the total tax base.

  9. TMT is correct. if you look simply at how much a house generates in the taxes that the locality uses for education – it’s a loss.

    School construction is the big cost with residential growth if a large number of new units have kids.

    this is why localities prefer age-restricted development ….

    but the important point here – is to understand what drives the costs with development…..

    and there is no way around it… local costs are 5K per student and more… and few typical homes generate that much is property taxes.

    that translates into a need for more property taxes…i.e. increases in property taxes ….

  10. Groveton Avatar

    “TMT is correct. if you look simply at how much a house generates in the taxes that the locality uses for education – it’s a loss.”.

    If I look simply at the Washington Redskins’ Tight Ends the Redskins are an 11-5 team. Unfortunately, the whole team was 6-10 last year.

    Looking at just one sliver of a situation is a very odd way to view the world. Kind of like going through life with blinders on.

  11. Groveton – I agree in part with your comments. Certainly any economic activity adds revenue to government (assuming such activity is not “off-the-books”). But which government? The building of a home in Northern Virginia creates taxable sales (most of which goes to Richmond), pays taxable wages (all of which goes to Richmond), and taxable profits (all of which goes to Richmond). The sale of a home generates taxable commissions and fees (all head south) and likely purchases of items of personal property (most of which goes south). In the broader analysis, which you correctly noted should be used, local governments in Virginia just don’t make out on residential construction, IMO. Schools are necessary and very expensive. Demand for public education, which I strongly support), makes residential growth problematic and, when the newcomers bring school-age children, a big money loser.

Leave a Reply