Supremes Reject “Compactness” Argument against 2011 Redistricting

Using the courts to reform Virginia’s politicians-pick-their-voters redistricting procedures got harder than ever, thanks to last week’s ruling by the Virginia Supreme Court.

One Virginia 2021, a nonpartisan redistricting reform group, had challenged the 2011 gerrymandering of five House of Delegates districts and six Senate districts on the grounds that they violated the state constitutional requirement that legislative districts must be “compact.” But the Supremes, concluding that reasonable, objective people can reach different conclusions about what constituts compactness, ruled against the challengers.

What Virginia house districts would look like if drawn by Brian Olson to be compact.

“We learn from today’s opinion that there’s a great deal of science in the redistricting process,” wrote Steve Emmert, publisher of the Virginia Appellate News & Analysis blog, immediately after the ruling, “but it’s a social science, not something as readily definable as physics. Both the challengers and the legislature … adduced expert testimony exploring the issue by various means of calculating compactness.”

The opinion written by Justice S. Bernard Goodwyn lays out the challengers’ argument in Rima Ford Vesilind versus the Virginia State Board of Elections as follows:

Article II… of the Constitution of Virginia … provides that legislative districts “shall be composed of contiguous and compact territory and shall be so constituted as to give, as nearly as is practicable, representation in proportion to the population of the district,” as well as federal requirements of “one person, one vote” and the Voting Rights Act. … The complaint asserts that “[w]hile the legislature may consider other rational public policy considerations, the mandates of the United States and Virginia Constitutions can never be subordinated to those considerations.”

The Challengers allege that the General Assembly “subordinated” the mandatory compactness requirements to other public policy considerations, and ignored compactness in favor of “nonconstitutional considerations,” such as “favor[ing] partisan interests” and “protect[in] particular incumbent[s],” “with the result that the Challenged Districts are not within any acceptable objective measures of compactness.”

During a three-day trial in March, Dr. Nicholas Mueller testified how he used software called Maptitude to draw an alternative district map to compare against the 2011 plan. He showed how it was possible to draw districts meeting the constitutional requirements while also refraining from splitting political subdivisions and refraining from pairing incumbents. Also, using the Reock, Polsby-Popper and Schwartsberg scores for measuring compactness, Dr. Michael McDonald showed how the districts enacted by the General Assembly degraded compactness scores by more than 50%.

However, wrote Goodwyn in his analysis of the testimony, “Compactness is a somewhat abstract concept.”

Determining compactness does not admit to a bright line approach in determining whether a legislative district is, in fact, compact. … Social scientists have developed at least 50 different methods of measuring compactness. The proliferation of measures does not provide clarity. It does exactly the opposite. In the social science community, there is no universal definition or consensus as to what constitutes the best measure for compact districts.

Furthermore, wrote Goodwyn:

Contrary to a core premise in Dr. McDonald’s test, the Constitution of Virginia does not require districts to be as compact as possible. [It] simply requires that districts “shall be … compact.” … As the Board observed, the compactness requirement is not based on the same type of objective comparative inquiry as the equal population requirement. …

Our Constitution speaks to the result of the redistricting process, and mandates that districts be compact in the end. It does not attempt to curtail the legislative process that creates the end result. Nor does it require that compactness be given priority over other considerations, much less establish a standard to determine whether the legislature gave proper priority to compactness.

While taking no issue with the Justice’s logic, blogger Emmert expressed his repugnance for the result. “I regard partisan redistricting as a form of blatant political corruption; as a cancer on our Republican form of government. The justices’ decision today means that we, the voters, are the surgeons who must remove this cancer. We can do so by telling our legislators that we insist upon it, and by voting for candidates who will pledge to commit the redistricting process to a nonpartisan group, as six states have already done.”


Share this article



ADVERTISEMENT

(comments below)



ADVERTISEMENT

(comments below)


Comments

6 responses to “Supremes Reject “Compactness” Argument against 2011 Redistricting”

  1. A member of the most-recent redistricting committee told me that the first principle of redistricting, agreed upon by both parties, is that the result of the new district definitions must be such that sitting legislators would be re-elected. Olson’s districts are far superior. We must raise this issue to a higher level using all forms of social media.

  2. djrippert Avatar
    djrippert

    Why is anyone surprised? The Supreme Court of Virginia is an appendage of The Imperial Clown Show. The clown elect the justices with no input or nomination by the governor. They then decide if the justices will be re-appointed when their 12 year term ends. “Be good little justices and vote the way we tell you to vote and maybe you get another term.”

    Virginia is for lovers? More like … Virginia is for lovers of institutionalized corruption.

    Definitions of compactness vary? Perhaps. Definitions of “tall” vary too. But any reasonable person would agree that Kareem Abdul-Jabbar is tall while Mickey Rooney was not tall. Those districts are not compact by any reasonable definition.

  3. CrazyJD Avatar
    CrazyJD

    It seems to me that referral of the issue to a “non-partisan” commission simply shifts the premium to obtaining a spot on the supposedly “non-partisan’ commission. What am I missing?

    1. djrippert Avatar
      djrippert

      As of 2015 Arizona and California had not only implemented non-partisan redistricting commissions but had held elections in the districts drawn by these commissions. In both cases the elections were far more competitive than was the case in legislature-drawn districts. I think both uses of non-partisan redistricting commissions were the result of citizen initiated referenda – something the Gods of Mt Richmond withhold from Virginians.

      https://www.nytimes.com/2015/07/02/upshot/independently-drawn-districts-have-proved-to-be-more-competitive.html

  4. TooManyTaxes Avatar
    TooManyTaxes

    You cannot have racial gerrymandering as required by federal law and compact districts focused on existing political subdivisions. Once you introduce some districts designed to allow the nominated candidate to win, you must have other districts that perform similar purposes for other political purposes.

  5. Steve Haner Avatar
    Steve Haner

    First, nobody should be surprised that the VA Supreme Court passed on an opportunity to pick a fight with the legislature. Both by precedent and by inclination the court rarely overturns legislative actions which are not blatantly unconstitutional.

    Second, I have a strong memory of a senior member of Attorney General Mary Sue Terry’s staff asserting to a three judge panel of the Fourth Circuit that the 1991 House of Delegates plan was drawn without political considerations. The judges laughed out loud, just hooted at her right to her face. But they found for the state and threw out the GOP lawsuit. So check that off too, the federal courts are equally deferential, except on Voting Rights Act arguments. They should be tougher on Baker v Carr issues IMHO.

    If the General Assembly wanted to adopt a compactness standard it could do so, and the courts would apply it. The current vague provisions are not an accident. I just don’t think the electorate in general understands it or cares that much. One-man one-vote is enforceable and the public gets that, and the Voting Rights provisions (whatever they are from day to day) are going to continue to drive the map, and the districts’ sections really should connect by actual roads (contiguity), but compactness to me is neither easy to define nor all that important.

    A rule against splitting any more precincts, however, would be a huge public winner. I’d allow variations from one man one vote to keep precincts intact. It is the precinct splitting that really is the heart of the most clever gerrymanders. Ban that.

    As the Democrats get closer and closer to taking back the House and Senate, don’t be surprised if the ardor for purity starts to fade. The VA GOP was on the receiving end of all this for a century. ‘Tis a great wheel……

Leave a Reply